Thoughts & Ideas

Monday, June 18, 2018

On the Functioning of Financial Markets


The article, “The Jan DhanYojana, four years later” in The Hindu dated 29th May 2018  though topical, and containing a few hard facts and figures, does not do justice to this very important subject and is way off in some of its conclusions. I will try and justify my contentions in this monograph. Please have a little patience.

Financial Inclusion is not just about opening bank accounts, using these accounts, and providing access to formal credit. To appreciate the importance of the concept of Financial Inclusion one needs to step back and see why and how strong, stable, and inclusive financial systems (banks and other financial intermediaries, finance companies, cooperative credit societies, capital market institutions etc. along with a strong regulatory framework) are essential for steady, accelerated, and equitable economic growth.  There is extensive literature on the subject starting from the 1960s, especially seminal ideas propounded by Gurley, Shaw, McKinnon et al. 

Naturally, for an inclusive financial system, all or most citizens need to be involved and be part of it. For example, people need to be able to ride the Bullet Train if they are to benefit from it. Just watching it whizzing past is not going to be of much help to either the people who built the Bullet Train, those who operate it, or the general public!

Developed and well-functioning financial systems, inter alia, (a) enable users to reduce the cost of exchanging real resources ie, through elimination of rigidities and reduction in transaction costs through both economies of scale and scope and use of technology by the financial intermediary; (b) leading to more efficient resource allocation, (c) provide the backbone of the payment mechanism, (d) helping to distribute and reduce risk for users (through tenor transformation, portfolio diversification, better monitoring through specialized skills etc), (e) enable easier accumulation of short & long term surpluses, (f) balance savings with need of funds over lifetime changes etc.  

Now starting with saving mechanisms, for any user of financial savings product (such as a JDY account) it should be safe, convenient, reliable, and cost effective. If a person has to spend half a day (that may mean losing a full day's earnings) to go to the bank to deposit or withdraw money he or she would obviously not use the facility. Add to that the paperwork in opening and operating the account. Or the transaction costs for small value receipts / payments using app-based software.  From the bank's point of view, transaction costs for servicing small accounts tend to be rather high and are naturally neglected - it just does not make commercial sense. Furthermore, if there aren’t steady and regular interactions between the intermediary and its customers, no trust based relationship can be built up leading to its eventual atrophy. 

The authors mention that 48% of bank holders have not done a single transaction during the past one year. This statistic by in itself hides the fact that there are have been reports of bankers putting in paltry sums of Rs.1 to Rs.10 in JDY accounts to show some transactions and lower number of zero balance accounts!1

As far as penetration of JDY accounts are concerned, the statistic that 80% of adults having bank accounts level mentioned in the article may need some scrutiny since the thrust of JDY is that all families should have functional bank accounts and the focus is not on individuals.

It also does not bring out the urgent need and pent up demand for savings mechanisms for small savers. In a study conducted by Stuart Rutherford2,  he discusses the service provided by Jyothi, a middle-aged semi-educated woman who makes her living as a peripatetic deposit collector in Vijayawada, whose clients are slum dwellers, mostly women. Jyothi has, over the years, built a good reputation as a safe pair of hands which could be trusted to take care of the savings of her clients. Jyothi’s accepted deposits of Rs.5/- every day so as to collect Rs.1100/- over 220 days. After which she returned Rs.1000/- to the depositor and retained Rs.100/- for her services. This translates to an annual negative interest rate of 30% per annum for rendering deposit services! Which I suppose is more than sufficient to make all our academics, policy makers, bureaucrats, politicians to start shouting Bharat Mata Ki Jai / Holy Marx / Jai Bhim or whatever and jump all over the place. But the fact remains that savers are willingly paying that kind of money since they value that service which the formal financial systems has failed to provide. Rutherford goes on to mention that slum dwellers in a neighbouring slum where there is no Jyothi at work actually envied Jyothi’s clients. Service providers for savings take different forms in our slums, villages, hamlets such as chit funds (formal & informal), Self Help Groups, and the numerous multi-level marketing companies which keep springing up from time to time all over the country.

All this springs from failure of our organized formal financial systems to provide such a service. The sad part is that this was not always so. Commercial bank’s did offer variations of something called Pygmy Deposits where deposit collectors made daily / weekly visits to collect the small savings and they provided this service without incurring a loss! For example, see the experience of Syndicate Bank discussed in Financial Innovations and Credit Market Evolution by V V Bhatt (EPW, Vol XXII, No 22, May 30, 1987). These were the days when banking operations were fully manual and as such the benefit of much lower marginal operating costs through use of digital technology was not available.

The thrust on promoting savings also does not take into account another critical aberration in our financial systems. Namely, due to widespread financial repression financial savings in formal institutions give a negative return in real terms! In this context, it is worth quoting the erstwhile Governor of RBI3 has gone on record in his speech wherein he mentioned that, “Many middle class savers value the high nominal interest rates on their fixed deposits, not realizing that their principal is eroding significantly every year”! Does that indicate as to why our society is subject to repeated onslaughts of Ponzi schemes all of which eventually and inevitably collapse. But during the course of their short existence promise an avenue for building up liquid financial saving which does not give negative returns in real terms.   And I am not even hinting on the effect of TDS on bank deposits which is extracted with clinical efficiency thanks to the superlative strength of Core Banking Systems.

Now let us see what happens in the absence of formal mechanisms for collecting small savings. They would have to be saved in kind since saving in cash would entail it losing value over time due to inflation if it was not lost, stolen, or borrowed away. If the saver managed to evade all these possibilities there is always the chance of it being spent on gambling or liquor. Saving in kind also has the added disadvantage of lacking fungibility and liquidity (the characteristics which gives fiat money its intrinsic value).

There also seems that there is another major and deep-seated myth among our academics and policy makers  -  that the poor do not and cannot have savings, or at least substantial savings. They need to appreciate that since earnings are highly variable and uncertain for the poor and they have absolutely no social security of any kind, savings are critical for survival. The small bits of savings is what enables the poor to survive from one misfortune to another. These savings take various interesting forms (again due to the failure of formal financial markets), such as, having reciprocal borrowing arrangements with friends and relatives, maintaining credit reserves with whom they provide services and products (by not immediately drawing down payments which are due), social practices such as neota, maintaining excess reserves of food grains and other items of inventory, keeping a few heads of goats, pigs, chicken etc which could either be sold or consumed as per dictates of circumstances etc.

This myth is also directly responsible for lack of attempts to design better savings mechanisms and for the stress on provision of credit as the proverbial magic wand for solving issues of “financial inclusion”.

Savers using the services of formal financial institutions like banks are cursed once again in another way. Since our bank’s are not making sufficient profits on the lending side of their business, they are naturally unwilling and unable to provide higher rates of returns on savings, especially in real terms! This suggests that the inefficiencies of the banking system and the borrowings from the formal financial sector are being subsidized by the deposit keeping community at large.

Now if one were to argue for promoting savings since it makes social sense,  one could also seek that the government should subsidize some portion of the operating costs – maybe through a reverse auction kind of mechanism. Banks could compete for achieving lowest cost for providing particular desired services, with the subsidy levels being based on this level. Since this subsidy would benefit society at large there would be much less scope for corruption. Otherwise banks will (and are becoming) become sick. Policies and practices which make banks sick will ultimately be of no good to either its customers or the economy. Continued good health of banks is essential for the real economy to remain robust - the reason they are so heavily regulated. Sick banks which have to be closed down also result in loss of institutional memory of the credit history of society, something which is impossible to recreate. For social and economic systems it is equivalent to heart failure in humans.

Technology may help in reducing transactions costs. Unfortunately, the system which has evolved over the last 30-40 years has resulted in traditional (PSU) banks lacking the requisite technical skills. Even worse, the one size fits all policy with industry wide equality in pay-scales, service conditions, internal processes, even the Core Banking System that they use, has stifled creativity and innovation. Something which is essential for growth of a vibrant financial system. An argument often given is that bank nationalization has enabled large increases in financial savings in the economy with its resultant positive effect on capital accumulation and economic growth. However, no one bothers to think about the cost of such savings mobilization – could the same levels of savings have been mobilized in more efficient ways, ie at lower costs?

The new generation pvt sector banks and the newest chips of the block - payment banks / small finance banks - either have too little incentives to pursue these market niches or are circumscribed by definition from benefiting from economies of scope, respectively!

Now coming to the stress laid on provision on easy access to credit, one needs to first appreciate that the ability or temperament to productively use credit is not very widely prevalent in any society. As such only a limited number of persons or families can benefit from access to credit. Furthermore, additional credit, cheap or costly, is no substitute for functional roads, primary health and education facilities, organized markets, or an administrative machinery which can prevent exploitative relationships. Even worse, there are well documented severe negative consequences in following a credit focused financial inclusion development strategy which include:

a)   Increasing levels of inequality in income and wealth since directed credit is cornered by the wealthy and politically powerful who thereby increase the capital at their disposal and become even more wealthy and powerful.  Larger loans means larger benefits, smaller loans means smaller benefits, and no loans means no benefits as far as the borrowers are concerned. And bulk of the people lie in the third category.

b)  Incentive to repay by borrowers who have preempted credit (typically through muscle or political power) is lower which not only further increases their economic and political status but simultaneously weakens the financial intermediaries who have lent the funds and have to book the consequent losses.

c)    Development of large and widespread corruption since the benefits are concentrated while the pain is widely spread, there is little focus or effort at tackling the resultant problems. Is it a wonder as to why our cooperative credit system produces some of our most corrupt politicians?

Another issue which hardly ever gets raised is the cost of capital. Interest rates reflect the cost of capital and it is well known that in India there is a very wide difference in the interest rates charged by most formal financial institutions / banks versus those charged by the fairly well organized informal institutions. The question that next arises is whether the informal sector is charging excessive rates or is the formal sector mis-pricing cost of capital.

Well interest rates in the informal markets are, prima facie, higher than formal markets. But would they still be considered higher cost after accounting for delays, the numerous trips, and the bribes with their associated real, direct and opportunity costs involved in accessing formal credit? The higher interest rates in informal markets also reflect the fact that (a) they are taking exposure to much higher risk levels, (b) provide kinds of services (other than credit) that formal intermediaries cannot even dream of, (c) have much less capital at their disposal as such require to charge higher rates to generate equivalent absolute amounts of return, (d) entire capital is in form of personal equity as such do not benefit from leverage (banks with Capital Adequacy Ratio of say 10% effectively have a leverage of  10:1) with its consequent benefits, and (e) during the slack season their capital is idle and does not generate any returns or meager returns.

Total cost of credit consists of basically two components, a fixed cost of accessing the credit which varies little with quantum of credit and a variable component, the actual interest rate. As such, for small value loans the average cost can be quite high since the fixed component has to be recovered from a smaller principal amount. This is another reason as to why informal lenders score over formal lenders, especially for small value loans and continue to be relevant. In this regard, Jerry R Ladman4 argues that “The partitioning of the market between BAB (a formal lender) and moneylenders shows the two lenders are providing different services. The moneylender provides credit quickly, on short-term basis, and in relatively small amount.”

Incidentally, the All India Rural Credit Survey (1951) (considered the gold plate for study of rural credit world-wide) does not support the prevalence of widespread use of exorbitant levels of interest rates commonly alleged to prevail in India! Data in this Survey indicated that village moneylenders grossed only an average of 11 percent per annum on their lending5!

Formal studies6 also suggest that the higher interest rates charged by the informal sector can be largely attributed to risks and administrative costs and not to monopoly power

Considering these factors, the conclusion arrived by most mainstream policy makers and the impression generally carried by most of us that informal money lenders are blood sucking thieves and rogues of the highest order seems not really substantiated by facts and logic. The reader may also care to remember that interest rates charged by many formal sector entities such as credit card companies and FinTecs involved in lending are not exactly cheap and more akin to rates charged by the informal sector.

Before concluding I would like to share a few quotes attributed to the ever-provocative Dale Adams, (Emeritus Professor of the Ohio State Rural Finance Program):

a)      "It is curious that the discomforts caused by a few people going into debt and not being able to repay tend to dominate general views held about financial intermediaries. The use of extreme cases to make general points is refined to an advanced art form in discussions about financial markets. Stories about poor farmers who lose their land to evil moneylenders are retold until people think that most loans go to default ….". (from Effects of Finance on Rural Development in Undermining Rural Development with Cheap Credit)

b)      … lenders provide loans, not gifts, and this creates obligations. When misfortunes strike, those obligations cannot always be met, putting the borrower into even greater jeopardy (from The Economics of Microfinance, by Beatriz Armendáriz de Aghion and Jonathan Morduch).

c)       … to the unwashed it (empowerment) conveys the impression that smearing a dab of additional debt on a poor woman will transform her into Super Woman. Those who insist on using this bloated term grossly overstate the contribution that indebting crusades play in easing poverty. More debt does not cure malaria or HIV/AIDS. It does not provide clean drinking water or prevent flooding. It does not improve law-and-order or eliminate weeds in a borrower’s crops. It does not make crops grow in barren soil or provide secure title to land that squatters occupy. It does not provide schools or teachers for the poor . . . (from The Economics of Microfinance, by Beatriz Armendáriz de Aghion and Jonathan Morduch).

There is much room for change / improvement in policy framework to enable our banks deliver on their capabilities. But such change should be based on an understanding of the nuances of functioning of financial markets and their main players such as banks. Propounding old, half-baked, hackneyed theories is not the way out – it is getting us into deeper mess.

1.   Government claims Jan Dhan Yojana was a big success. Here’s a reality check by Mayank Jain, The Scroll, 6th September 2017;  & Jan Dhan Yojana: One Rupee Balance and the Dormancy-Duplication Problem by Anuj Srivas, The Wire, 14/09/2017.
2.     The Poor & their Money, Stuart Rutherford, Oxford India Paperbacks
3.    Policy & Evidence.  Inaugural Address by Dr. Raghuram Rajan, Governor, Reserve Bank of India at the 10th Statistics Day Conference 2016, Reserve Bank of India on July 26, 2016, Mumbai 
4.    Ladman, Jerry R. Loan-Transaction Costs, Credit Rationing, and Market Structure: The Case of Bolivia, in Undermining Rural Development with Cheap Credit.
5.   All-India Rural Credit Survey, Vol. 1, The Survey Report, pt. 2, Bombay, Reserve Bank of India, 1957, pp. 490-91. - quoted by David H Penny in Rural Financial Markets in Developing Countries, page 66.
6.   Bottomley, Anthony. Interest Rate Determination in Underdeveloped Rural Areas, American Journal of Agricultural Economics 1975;
7.  Long, Millard F. Interest Rates and the Structure of Agricultural Credit Markets, Oxford Economic Papers 1968.

0 Comments:

Post a Comment

Subscribe to Post Comments [Atom]

<< Home